Tuesday , March 19 2024
Home / Post-Keynesian / The Tractor-Corn Model: A Start

The Tractor-Corn Model: A Start

Summary:
1.0 Introduction In my ROBE article, I consider fluke switch points arising from perturbations of coefficients of production in the Samuelson-Gargenani model, but in the case with only circulating capital. An obvious generalization is to consider fixed capital. This generalization is simplified by restricting oneself to the case in which machines operate with constant efficiency. Steedman (2020) analyzes this case, and this post is a start on working through elements of the corn-tractor model he leaves as homework. I do not know how far I will go in rewriting my paper for this case. 2.0 Technology for a Technique In the model, corn is produced by labor working working with a specified type of tractor. And that type of tractor is itself produced by labor working with that type of

Topics:
Robert Vienneau considers the following as important: , ,

This could be interesting, too:

Robert Vienneau writes To Do: Perverse Switch Points And The Economic Life Of A Machine

Robert Vienneau writes Labor Values And Invariants

Robert Vienneau writes Two Special Cases For The Labor Theory Of Value

Robert Vienneau writes Variation On An Example From Schefold

1.0 Introduction

In my ROBE article, I consider fluke switch points arising from perturbations of coefficients of production in the Samuelson-Gargenani model, but in the case with only circulating capital. An obvious generalization is to consider fixed capital. This generalization is simplified by restricting oneself to the case in which machines operate with constant efficiency. Steedman (2020) analyzes this case, and this post is a start on working through elements of the corn-tractor model he leaves as homework. I do not know how far I will go in rewriting my paper for this case.

2.0 Technology for a Technique

In the model, corn is produced by labor working working with a specified type of tractor. And that type of tractor is itself produced by labor working with that type of tractor.

Each type of tractor defines a technique, where a technique is specified by six parameters:

  • a: The number of tractors (of a given age) whose services are used for a year in producing a new tractor.
  • b: The person-years of labor needed to work with tractors (of a given age) to produce a new tractor.
  • n: The number of years a tractor lasts when used in producing new tractors.
  • α: The number of tractors (of a given age) whose services are used for a year in producing a bushel of corn.
  • β: The person-years of labor needed to work with tractors (of a given age) to produce corn.
  • ν: The number of years a tractor lasts when used in producing corn.

The notation is Steedman's, borrowed from J. R. Hicks. I see that if I keep this notation, I will have to drop my usual practice, in honor of Joan Robinson, of using lowercase Greek letters to refer to a technique.

Consider, for a technique, the (n + ν)-element row vector of labor coefficients a0, the (n + ν) x (n + ν) matrix A of input coefficients, and the (n + ν) x (n + ν) matrix B of output coefficients. This vector and these matrices have a block structure:

a0 =bb (uT)1,n - 2bββ (uT)1,ν - 2β
A = 001,n - 20001,ν - 20
a01,n - 20α01,ν - 20
0n - 2, 1a In - 2,n - 20n - 2, 10n - 2,10n - 2,ν - 20n - 2,1
001,n - 2a001,ν - 20
0ν - 2,10ν - 2,n - 20ν - 2,10ν - 2,1α Iν - 2,ν - 20ν - 2,1
001,n - 20001,ν - 2α
B = 001,n - 201(uT)1,ν - 21
1(uT)1,n - 21001,ν - 20
a01,n - 20001,ν - 20
0n - 2,1a In - 2,n - 20n - 2, 10n - 2, 10n - 2,ν - 20n - 2, 1
001,n - 20α01,ν - 20
0ν - 2,10ν - 2,n - 20ν - 2,10ν - 2,1α Iν - 2,ν - 20ν - 2,1

Obviously, HTML defeated me here. I is the identity matrix, and u is a column unit vector.

Each element of a0 and each column of A and B correspond to a process of production. The first n columns constitute the tractor sector, and the remaining ν columns are the corn sector. I assume constant returns to scale and that each process requires a year to complete. a0, j is the person-years of labor that enters the jth process per unit-level of operations. The jth column of A is the inputs consumed by the process, and the jth column of B is the outputs. The first row index is for corn. The first row of A is zero, since corn is not used as an input in any process. The second row index is for new tractors. The remaining row indices are for old tractors. Once a tractor is used in tbe production of tractors, it can no longer be used in producing corn. Likewise, a tractor used in the corn sector cannot be transferred to the tractor sector.

3.0 An Annuity

Consider an annuity cn(r) bought for a dollar at the start of a year. This annuity pays out the sum cn(r) at the end of the first year, at the end of the second year, and so on through the end of the nth year. This arrangement implicitly specifies an interest rate r which equates the cost and the present value of the payments:

1 = cn(r)/(1 + r) + cn(r)/[(1 + r)2] + ... + cn(r)/[(1 + r)n]

A bit of algebra reveals that the payments for the annuity are given by the following formula:

cn(r) = r (1 + r)n/[(1 + r)n - 1]

The limit as the interest rate approaches zero can be found by L'Hôpital's rule. It is:

cn(0) = 1/n

I need these formulas below.

4.0 The Quantity System

Now I want to consider a steady state in which the economy grows at a uniform rate of 100 g percent. Let the column vector q specify the level of operation of each process. I postulate that q has the following form:

qT = [q1, q1/(1 + g), ..., q1/(1 + g)n - 1, q2, q2/(1 + g), ..., q2/(1 + g)ν - 1]

where q1 and q2 are variables to be determined. Let e1 be the first column of the identity matrix. Consumption in a steady-state is c(g) e1, where:

c(g) e1 = [B - (1 + g) A] q

Expanding the first element of the column vectors on both sides, one gets:

c(g) = (1 + g) q2/cν(g)

The second element yields:

0 = {[(1 + g)/cn(g)] - (1 + g) a} q1 - (1 + g) α q2

Or:

0 = [1 - a cn(g)] q1 - α cn(g) q2

Given g, the above is a linear equation in q1 and q2. New tractors do not enter into consumption. Quantity flows are specified such that one person-year of labor is employed:

a0q = 1

Or:

(1 + g) b q1/cn(g) + (1 + g) β q2/cν(g) = 1

Or:

b cν(g) q1 + β cn(g) q2 = cn(g) cν(g)/(1 + g)

A linear system of two equations in two unknowns, given the rate of growth, has now been derived.

The system is easily solved:

q1 = α cn(g) cν(g) /{[β + αbcν(g) - aβcn(g)](1 + g)}
q2 = [1 - acn(g)] cν(g)/{[β + αbcν(g) - aβcn(g)](1 + g)}

Consumption per worker (in units of bushels corn per person-year) is:

c(g) = [1 - acn(g)]/[β + αbcν(g) - aβcn(g)]

In a comparison of steady states, consumption per worker is higher if the rate of growth is lower. The dependence of the denominator on the rate of growth vanishes under the special case in which:

a cn(g)/b = α cν(g)/β

Somehow, the above says that the organic composition of capital does not vary between the tractor and the corn sectors. The tradeoff, however, between consumption per worker and the rate of growth is still not linear. The maximum rate of growth, G, is the smallest non-negative real solution to:

0 = 1 - a cn(G)

Consumption per worker in a stationary state is:

c(0) = [n - a]ν/[nνβ + αbn - aβν]

One might use the above to discuss the capital-intensity of a technique. If the technique with one type of tractor is more capital-intensive than the technique with another type, one would expect c(0) to be higher with the first type.

5.0 The Price System

I now consider prices. Let p be a row vector of prices, w the wage, and r the rate of profits. In matrix form, the price equations are:

p A (1 + r) + w a0 = p B

A bushel corn is the numeraire:

p e1 = 1

The above consists of a system of (n + ν + 1) equations for (n + ν + 2) variables. The system has one degree of freedom. Labor is advanced, and wages are paid out of the surplus at the end of the year. A tractor of each age and history has a seperate price.

I now rewrite the price equations for the first time. The price of a bushel cotn is unity, and p represents thd price of a new machine. pm,j is the price of a j-year old tractor in the tractor sector. pc,j is the price of a j-year old tractor in the corn sector. The n equations for the tractor sector are:

p a (1 + r) + w b = p + pm,1a
pm,1a (1 + r) + w b = p + pm,2a

...

pm,n - 1a (1 + r) + w b = p

The ν equations for the corn sector are:

p α (1 + r) + w β = 1 + pc,1 α
pc,1 α (1 + r) + w β = 1 + pc,2a

...

pc,ν - 1 α (1 + r) + w β = 1

Consider the equations for the machine sector. Multiply the first equation by (1 + r)n - 1, the second equation by (1 + r)n - 2, and so on, until the last equation is multiplied by (1 + r)0.Sum these equations:

p a (1 + r)n + w b [1 + (1 + r) + ... + (1 + r)n - 1] = p [1 + (1 + r) + ... + (1 + r)n - 1]

The prices for old tractors appear on both sides of successive equations with the same coefficient and drop out. A similiar procedure for the corn sector yields:

p α (1 + r)ν + w β [1 + (1 + r) + ... + (1 + r)ν - 1] = [1 + (1 + r) + ... + (1 + r)ν - 1]

So far, this procedure works if tractors do not have constant efficiency. The next step requires that, though. The price equations become:

p a cn(r) + w b = p
p α cν(r) + w β = 1

Fpr both the quantity and the price system, a set of (n + ν) equations is reduced to two equations in which (quantities or prices) of old tractors do not enter. The charge for a tractor is that of an annuity that pays out for each year of the tractor's life.

The price system is easily solved. The price of a new tractor is:

p = b/[β + αbcν(r) - aβcn(r)]

Under the special case of equal organic compositions of capital, the ratio of a price of a new tractor to a bushel corn is the ratio of direct labor inputs. Presumably, prices are also proportional to labor values in this special case. The wage curve is:

w = [1 - acn(r)]/[β + αbcν(r) - aβcn(r)]

I have already discussed the wage curve under the guise of the tradeoff between consumption per worker and the rate of growth. The maximum rate of profits R is identical to the maximum rate of growth G.

6.0 Conclusion

Steedman (2020) avoids writing about almost all of the above or leaves it as an exercise for the reader. Basically, I have derived Steedman's first five numbered equations. Some of this is in Chapter 10 of Sraffa (1960).

References
  • Gargenani, Pierangelo. 1970. Heterogeneous capital, the production function and the theory of distribution. Review of Economic Studies 37 (3): 407-436..
  • Samuelson, Paul A. 1962. Parable and realism in capital theory: the surrogate production function. Review of Economic Studies 29 (3): 193-206.
  • Steedman, Ian. 2020. Fixed capital in the corn-tractor model. Metroeconomica 71: 49-56.
  • Vienneau, Robert L. 2018. Normal forms for switch point patterns. Review of Behavioral Economics 5 (2): 169-195.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *