Sunday , December 22 2024
Home / Post-Keynesian / On Sraffian Subsytems And Labor Values

On Sraffian Subsytems And Labor Values

Summary:
1.0 Introduction I recently stumbled across McKiernan (2017), an Austrian response to Sraffa's book. This is a weird working paper. He works through Sraffa, with apparently no knowledge of all the textbooks explaining the book. McKiernan correctly notes that Sraffa provides little context about his points. And the mathematics is not always explicit. Naturally, McKiernan makes mistakes. If he ever revisits this, I think he would want to break it up into several papers. (Fabra (1991) is the strangest published response to Sraffians of which I know.) I only want to focus on one point, Sraffian subsytems. But before doing that, let me at least point out something insightful in McKiernan's paper. He points out one of what I later call a fluke case: However, Sraffa makes no note of cases

Topics:
Robert Vienneau considers the following as important: ,

This could be interesting, too:

Robert Vienneau writes Another Hayekian Triangle Not Supporting The Austrian School

Robert Vienneau writes Adam Smith, David Ricardo, And The Labor Theory Of Value

Robert Vienneau writes Roger Garrison On The Inadequacy Of Hayekian Triangles

Robert Vienneau writes The Production Of Commodities And The Structure Of Production: An Example

1.0 Introduction

I recently stumbled across McKiernan (2017), an Austrian response to Sraffa's book. This is a weird working paper. He works through Sraffa, with apparently no knowledge of all the textbooks explaining the book. McKiernan correctly notes that Sraffa provides little context about his points. And the mathematics is not always explicit. Naturally, McKiernan makes mistakes. If he ever revisits this, I think he would want to break it up into several papers. (Fabra (1991) is the strangest published response to Sraffians of which I know.)

I only want to focus on one point, Sraffian subsytems. But before doing that, let me at least point out something insightful in McKiernan's paper. He points out one of what I later call a fluke case:

However, Sraffa makes no note of cases in which a scarcity of land is offset by using a more expensive method of production, and that employment meets present desire for the product exactly when applied to all available land, so that only one method is used. In this case, two variables, pcorn and ρ, correspond to one equation. (p. 22)

I think I could also construct a fluke case with intensive rent, which is closer to his point.

2.0 A Criticism Of Subsystems

McKieran mistakenly asserts:

But consider the pricing of a commodity that were not produced in surplus, as could happen in these models with a purely infrastructural commodity. A sub-system for this commodity would have a net production of 0, but these models have all presumed a need for active renewal, so there would be an expenditure of labor. If returns to scale were co-incident, so that the sub-system might be embodied, that sub-system standing alone would produce a wage of 0, but wages are presumed to be shared across sub-systems (else Sraffa’s argument falls apart). Hence, it appears that prices of commodities of this infrastructural sort must be whatever one makes of division by 0. (p. 8)

(If McKieran ever revisits this, I wish he would give a more explicit and formal definition of co-incident returns. I think I get his point, but I do not think I have ever seen this notion in the economics literature.)

Anyways, if the net output of a commodity is zero, the decomposition of the given quantity flows into Sraffian subsytems, with nothing left over, will result in no labor being directed towards producing a net output of that commodity. So one rather gets a quotient of zero divided by zero, not a division of a positive quantity of zero. Nevertheless, one can still find a Sraffian subsystem for producing that commodity.

3.0 A Decomposition of One Set of Quantity Flows

I take an example from my FAQ on the Labor Theory of Value. Consider an economy with the observed quantity flows shown in Table 1. In this little model economy, wheat, iron, and labor are used to produce a net output of 500 quarters of wheat and 8 tons iron. From the postulated observations, one cannot tell whether iron is somehow consumed or whether this economy is undergoing steady growth. Given, say, the real wage, one can calculate prices of production. But many questions are not adressed here.

Table 1: Given Quantity Flows
InputsOutput
74 qr. wheat & 37 t. iron & 592 worker.->592 qr. wheat
18 qr. wheat & 3 t. iron & 48 workers->48 t. iron

I find Leontief coefficients of production useful. Table 2 results from dividing the first of Table 1 by 592 qr. wheat and the second row by 48 t. iron.

Table 2: Leontief Coefficients
InputsOutput
1/8 qr. & 1/16 t. & 1 workers->1 qr. wheat
3/8 qr. & 1/16 t. & 1 workers->1 t. iron

Suppose these coefficients of production are used to calculate inputs when gross outputs of are approximately 588.2 quarters wheat and 39.2 tons iron. Table 3 results. The net output of the wheat subsytem is 500 quarters wheat, produced from an input of 32000/51 workers. That is 64/51 ≈ 1.25 workers are embodied in each quarter of wheat.

Table 3: Wheat Subsystem
InputsOutput
1250/17 ≈ 73.5 qr. & 625/17 ≈ 36.8 t. & 10000/17 ≈ 588.2 workers10000/17 qr. wheat
250/17 ≈ 14.7 qr. & 125/51 ≈ 2.5 t. & 2000/51 ≈ 39.2 workers2000/51 t. iron

Table 4 shows the iron subsystem. In this subsystem, 640/51 ≈ 12.5 workers produce a net output of 8 tons iron. In other words, 80/51 ≈ 1.57 workers are embodied in each ton iron.

Table 4: Iron Subsystem
InputsOutput
8/17 ≈ 0.5 qr. & 4/17 ≈ 0.2 t. & 64/17 ≈ 3.8 workers64/17 qr. wheat
56/17 ≈ 3.3 qr. & 28/51 ≈ 0.5 t. & 448/51 ≈ 8.8 workers448/51 t. iron

The quantity flows shown in Tables 3 and 4 add up to the quantity flows in Table 1. In these subsystems are thought of as operating side-by-side, total quantity flows are as in the observed economy. No assumptions on returns to scale are needed for this decomposition into subsystems.

4.0 A Decomposition of Another Set of Quantity Flows

I now want to consider another set of quantity flows that might be observed. Suppose these quantity flows are as in Table 5. The net output of this economy consists of 500 quarters wheat. For ease of calculation, I have used the same coefficients of production as in Table 2. They very well could be different since gross outputs vary from those in Table 1. If coefficients of production vary, so do returns to scale. Anyways, in this example, the net output of iron is zero. But even so, one can find here a subsystem for producing iron.

Table 5: Another Set of Quantity Flows
InputsOutput
1250/17 ≈ 73.5 qr. & 625/17 ≈ 36.8 t. & 10000/17 ≈ 588.2 workers10000/17 qr. wheat
250/17 ≈ 14.7 qr. & 125/51 ≈ 2.5 t. & 2000/51 ≈ 39.2 workers2000/51 t. iron

Consider the quantity flows shown in Table 6. The net output is 500 quarters wheat and -8 tons iron. This is not a Sraffian subsystem. It is unbalanced. But these quantity flows are constructed from the same coefficients of production as manifested in Table 5.

Table 6: Unbalanced Quantity Flows
InputsOutput
1242/17 ≈ 73.1 qr. & 621/17 ≈ 36.5 t. & 9936/17 ≈ 584.5 workers9936/17 qr. wheat
194/17 ≈ 11.4 qr. & 97/51 ≈ 1.9 t. & 1552/51 ≈ 30.4 workers1552/51 t. iron

Now consider what quantity flows result from subtracting those in Table 6 from those in Table 5. Table 7 results. This is the same subsystem for producing iron as shown in Table 4. Even though the net output of iron in the observed quantity flows in Table 5 is zero, one can still find in them an iron subsystem.

Table 7: The Iron Subsystem Again
InputsOutput
8/17 ≈ 0.5 qr. & 4/17 ≈ 0.2 t. & 64/17 ≈ 3.8 workers64/17 qr. wheat
56/17 ≈ 3.3 qr. & 28/51 ≈ 0.5 t. & 448/51 ≈ 8.8 workers448/51 t. iron
5.0 Results

No assumptions on returns to scale are made in analytically decomposing the observed quantity flows into subsystems.

Given observed physical quantity flows, one can ask how much more labor would be employed if net output of the economy was increased by a small quantity of a specified commodity. In other words, each commodity has an employment multiplier, to use the jargon of Leontief analysis. If non-constant returns to scale do not prevail, the error in this calculation will become more pronounced as the specified quantity increases. An insight behind the differential calculus is that, for continuous functions, a small enough variation has an approximately linear effect.

Reference

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *