Sunday , December 22 2024
Home / Post-Keynesian / Harrod-Neutral Technical Change And The Choice Of Technique

Harrod-Neutral Technical Change And The Choice Of Technique

Summary:
Figure 1: Variation in the Maximum Wage and the Cost-Minimizing Technique with Time1.0 Introduction I thought I would revisit the application of my analysis of fluke switch points to an example of Harrod-neutral technical change. Two techniques are assumed to experience Harrod-neutral technical change. The same commodities are produced with both techniques. No capital goods are produced for one technique that are unproduced in the other. Consequently, the techniques have no processes in common. At least two processes must be available in each industry. So more than two techniques must exist. I think these ideas could be worked up into something. I will probably spend some time toying with the example. 2.0 Technology This economy produces a single consumption good, called corn. Corn

Topics:
Robert Vienneau considers the following as important: ,

This could be interesting, too:

Robert Vienneau writes The Production Of Commodities And The Structure Of Production: An Example

Robert Vienneau writes A Derivation Of Prices Of Production With Linear Programming

Robert Vienneau writes Reswitching Pattern In Corn-Tractor Model

Robert Vienneau writes Goal: Perturb Special Case Of Steedman’s Corn-Tractor Model

Harrod-Neutral Technical Change And The Choice Of Technique
Figure 1: Variation in the Maximum Wage and the Cost-Minimizing Technique with Time
1.0 Introduction

I thought I would revisit the application of my analysis of fluke switch points to an example of Harrod-neutral technical change. Two techniques are assumed to experience Harrod-neutral technical change. The same commodities are produced with both techniques. No capital goods are produced for one technique that are unproduced in the other. Consequently, the techniques have no processes in common. At least two processes must be available in each industry. So more than two techniques must exist.

I think these ideas could be worked up into something. I will probably spend some time toying with the example.

2.0 Technology

This economy produces a single consumption good, called corn. Corn is also a capital good, that is, a produced commodity used in the production of other commodities. In fact, iron, steel, and corn are capital goods in this example. So three industries exist. One produces iron, another produces steel, and the last produces corn. Two processes exist in each industry for producing the output of that industry. Each process exhibits Constant Returns to Scale (CRS) and is characterized by coefficients of production. Coefficients of production (Table 1) specify the physical quantities of inputs required to produce a unit output in the specified industry. All processes require a year to complete, and the inputs of iron, steel, and corn are all consumed over the year in providing their services so as to yield output at the end of the year. The technology is specified for a specific moment in time, and improves over time.

Table 1: The Technology
InputIron
Industry
Steel
Industry
Corn
Industry
abcdef
Labor(15/2) et32 et(13/2) et60 et(15/2) et55 et
Iron1/62/51/2001/10010
Steel1/2001/4001/43/1001/4
Corn1/3001/3001/300000

A technique consists of a process in each industry. Table 2 specifies the eight techniques that can be formed from the processes specified by the technology. If you work through this example, you will find that to produce a net output of one bushel corn, inputs of iron, steel, and corn all need to be produced to reproduce the capital goods used up in producing that bushel.

Table 2: Techniques
TechniqueProcesses
Alphaa, c, e
Betaa, c, f
Gammaa, d, e
Deltaa, d, f
Epsilonb, c, e
Zetab, c, f
Etab, d, e
Thetab, d, f

The Alpha and Theta techniques each undergo Harrod-neutral technical progress. The labor coefficients for the Alpha technique decrease at the the rate φ and those for the Theta technique decrease at the rate σ. The other techniques consist of a mixture of processes from these two techniques.

3.0 Prices of Production

A system of equations can be set out for prices of production, for each technique,at any moment of time. I assume that net output consists of a bushel corn, and that this net output is the numeraire. Wages are paid out of the surplus product after the harvest. Given competitive conditions, the same rate of profits are obtained in each industry.

These assumptions are sufficient to determine the wage and the prices of produced commodities, for each technique, at the given moment in time, as a function of the rate of profits.

4.0 The Choice of Technique

The cost-minimizing technique at a moment of time can be found by constructing the wage frontier as the outer envelope of the wage curves for the eight techniques. Given the rate of profits, the cost-minimizing technique maximizes the wage. Given the wage, it maximizes the rate of profits.

Figure 1, at the top of this post, and Figure 2 depict how the dependence of the cost-minimizing technique on distribution varies with time. These graphs are drawn for the indicated rates of neutral technical progress in the Alpha and Theta techniques. Figure 1 graphs the maximum wage and the wage at each switch point on the frontier. Figure 2 graphs the rate of profits, both the maximum and at each switch point on the frontier. Figure 2 also shows the rate of profits at switch points between -100 percent and zero. The thin vertical lines partition time into numbered regions. Each partition corresponds to a fluke switch point.

Harrod-Neutral Technical Change And The Choice Of Technique
Figure 2: Variation in the Maximum Rate of Profits and the Cost-Minimizing Technique with Time

The ranking of techniques by the maximum rate of profits does not vary with time. At the maximum rate of profits, the wage is zero. Variations in labor coefficients do not matter. In this case, the Alpha technique remains cost-minimizing for all time at a wage of zero. It is not necessary, in general, that the cost-minimizing technique at a zero wage, be one of those experiencing Harrod-neutral technical change. For other coefficients of production, the Beta technique, for example, could be cost-minimizing at a zero wage.

In general, the cost-minimizing technique at the maximum wage starts with the technique with the slowest rate of neutral technical progress. Over time, the cost-minimizing technique becomes the technique with the largest rate of technical progress.

In the example, the Alpha technique is cost-minimizing at the start of time, whatever the distribution of income. Region 1 illustrates this lack of dependence of the cost-minimizing technique on distribution. the Alpha technique remains cost-minimizing for all time at a wage of zero. Since the rate of Harrod-neutral technical progress is assumed to be greater for the Theta technique, eventually Theta is cost-minimizing at the maximum wage. One can see the effects of technical progress with the exponential growth of the maximum wage in Figure 2.

Consider Region 7 in the Figures. At a non-fluke switch point, only one process changes in the cost-minimizing technique. As the wage increases, the corn-producing process changes at the switch point between Alpha and Beta. At the second switch-point with increasing wages, the cost-minimizing process in steel production changes. Finally, at the switch point between Delta and Theta, the cost-minimizing process in in iron production changes.

In Region 6, which process changes first, with increasing wages, in iron and steel production varies. The iron process varies at the switch point between Beta and Zeta. At a higher wage, the steel process in the cost-minimizing technique varies at the switch point between Zeta and Theta. The partition between Region 6 and Region 7 has a fluke switch point in which the iron and steel-producing processes change simultaneously.

Region 2 exhibits reswitching between the Alpha and Beta techniques. The switch point at the lower wage is an example of capital-reversing, also known as a positive real Wicksell effect. Around this switch point, a higher wage is associated with the employment of more labor per unit of net output. It also exhibits the reverse substitution of labor. In Regions 2, 3, and 4, the labor coefficient in Process f exceeds the labor coefficient in Process e. A higher wage at this switch point between Alpha and Beta is associated with greater employment per unit of gross corn output.

5.0 Conclusion

The introduction of switch points and the variation in the cost-minimizing technique at the maximum wage is, in some sense, a general property of technology formed out of techniques experiencing Harrod-neutral technical progress. With time, switch points are introduced as fluke cases. These fluke cases need create examples of reswitching, capital-reversing, reverse labor substitution, or process recurrence. But they do in the example.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *