Sunday , November 17 2024
Home / Video / Kingston University Becoming an Economist Lecture 03: The Austrians

Kingston University Becoming an Economist Lecture 03: The Austrians

Summary:
The core question posed by Austrian economists (beginning with Menger) was “how does innovation and change occur in a market economy?”. Though they shared many of the same concepts as the mainstream–supply and demand analysis, and the belief that “value” was subjective rather than objective–they diverged on many others, especially on how much knowledge could ...

Topics:
Steve Keen considers the following as important:

This could be interesting, too:

Robert Vienneau writes Another Hayekian Triangle Not Supporting The Austrian School

Joel Eissenberg writes Access to medical care: right or privilege?

NewDealdemocrat writes Production turns more negative

Bill Haskell writes Lawler: Early Read on Existing Home Sales in October











The core question posed by Austrian economists (beginning with Menger) was “how does innovation and change occur in a market economy?”.



Though they shared many of the same concepts as the mainstream–supply and demand analysis, and the belief that “value” was subjective rather than objective–they diverged on many others, especially on how much knowledge could be had about the economy.



Neoclassicals began with attempting to analyse the economy as if it were in equilibrium, because their analytic tools at the time could not handle a disequilibrium position. Over time, for reasons explained in the last lecture in this series, they became wedded to the proposition that the economy itself was in equilibrium, or would always return to it rapidly after any “exogenous shock”. As part of explaining how this would happen, they invented the concept of “rational expectations”, which assumed that a “rational person” had a model of the economy in his head that let him accurately predict the future of the economy.



Austrians regaled at this assumption, instead arguing that real people have limited knowledge even of the present, and the Neoclassical assumption that they could predict the future was not a “simplifying assumption”, but a dangerous fantasy (Keynes was in complete agreement with his Austrian rival Hayek on this point, and the rejection of this fantasy by some of Keynes’s followers led to the formation of the Post Keynesian school, which I discuss in the next lecture).



Austrians instead argued that people have very limited knowledge of the present, and that the great advantage of the market was that it assembled this limited individual knowledge into something meaningful in the aggregate. But this also meant that the economy would never be in perfect equilibrium, and entrepreneurs could then profit by exploiting the difference between where the market currently was, and what would actually be its equilibrium.



Schumpeter is not regarded as an Austrian economist by today’s school of Austrian economics, but I regard his analysis and vision as very compatible with theirs, and giving a great explanation of how innovation occurs in a capitalist economy. I therefore devote much of the lecture to discussing his explanation of how transformational change occurs, thanks to entrepreneurs disturbing what he calls “the circular flow” of the equilibrium model developed by the Neoclassicals.



Steve Keen
Steve Keen (born 28 March 1953) is an Australian-born, British-based economist and author. He considers himself a post-Keynesian, criticising neoclassical economics as inconsistent, unscientific and empirically unsupported. The major influences on Keen's thinking about economics include John Maynard Keynes, Karl Marx, Hyman Minsky, Piero Sraffa, Augusto Graziani, Joseph Alois Schumpeter, Thorstein Veblen, and François Quesnay.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *