Progressives and social democrats should be fighting them tooth and nail, not blithely embracing them. by Steve Roth Originally Posted at Wealth Economics The spreadsheet behind the tables and graphs here is available on request. Drop me a line in the comments or elsewhere. Following the community of Socks (đ§Šs) or âsocial democratsâ out there on the interwebs (this is definitely my economic tribe), in articles, and in books, thereâs a particular stance on a particular issue that I find perplexing, even anti-progressive. Theyâre generally quite keen on using âvalue-addedâ consumption/sales taxes (VATs) to fund a robust social-benefits or âwelfareâ system. (Viz: this out recently from Matt Bruenig and the Peopleâs Policy Project. Thanks to
Topics:
Steve Roth considers the following as important: politics, US EConomics, VATs
This could be interesting, too:
NewDealdemocrat writes Retail Real Sales
Angry Bear writes Planned Tariffs, An Economy Argument with Political Implications
Joel Eissenberg writes Will DOGE be an exercise in futility?
Bill Haskell writes The spiderâs web called Healthcare Insurance
Progressives and social democrats should be fighting them tooth and nail, not blithely embracing them.
by Steve Roth
Originally Posted at Wealth Economics
The spreadsheet behind the tables and graphs here is available on request. Drop me a line in the comments or elsewhere.
Following the community of Socks (đ§Šs) or âsocial democratsâ out there on the interwebs (this is definitely my economic tribe), in articles, and in books, thereâs a particular stance on a particular issue that I find perplexing, even anti-progressive. Theyâre generally quite keen on using âvalue-addedâ consumption/sales taxes (VATs) to fund a robust social-benefits or âwelfareâ system. (Viz: this out recently from Matt Bruenig and the Peopleâs Policy Project. Thanks to Matt for discussing this and disagreeing with me on it.)
Itâs perplexing to me because consumption taxes, on their face, are the most regressive taxes out there. Poorer people generally pay a higher share of their income on a sales tax, for instance (compared to richer people), than with an income tax, much less a wealth tax. Why would full-throated progressive Socks support and embrace that?
When I ask, I get four main answers.
Financial/economic: âThereâs just not enough money at the top to fund the scope of the programs we need.â
Political: âWithout broad participation (read: contributions) across the income/wealth spectrum, you canât assemble or maintain the political coalition to support robust social democracy.â
Historical: âAll the robust, successful social democracies out there are heavily funded by VATs.â Think northern Europe, especially Scandinavia.
Policy-analytical. âThe goal is a total tax/transfer system thatâs progressive. Focusing on the progressivity of particular tax or transfer programs misses the point.â
For me, that last point misses the point, which is not just providing high levels of material well-being at the bottom of the spectrum (which I of course strongly support). Itâs about addressing and reversing the worldâs extreme and increasing concentrations of income and especially wealth. Thatâs the core, long-term structural issue that needs fixing. VAT-and-transferâs laser-focus on the bottom leaves the top to happily go along on its very merry way.
That reality exists even (especially!) in strong social democracies that used to have very progressive taxes, but abandoned them for VATs starting in the â60s. Socks are fond of saying that every billionaire is a policy failure, but . . .
To address that structural issue, we need to, quite simply, seize the wealth and income. (Fuggedabout âthe means of production.â That overwhelmingly consists of.âŠpeople. Are you gonna âseize the peopleâ?) Willie Suttonâs line pertains here in spades, especially on top-end wealth: âThatâs where the money is.â
If reducing the concentration of wealth, income, and hence power is an important progressive goal (or even the progressive goal), then the preference for VATs crashes on some very simple facts, and some very simple arithmetic. In the US as an example, the top 20% of households holds 74% of financial assets and 68% of total assets, receives 50% of income, but only does 35% of spending.
Do the arithmetic. Flat consumption taxes are inevitably regressive relative to income, much less wealth.
There are ways to make VATs less regressive. Donât tax food purchases, for instance. But itâs a very deep regressive hole to climb out of. To get a sense of that: if the bottom quintile pays a 10% consumption tax, what rate would other quintiles have to pay, to make the tax merely proportional (non-progressive) relative to income and wealth?
Should we tax top-earners 25 cents for every dollar they spend? 78 cents? Good luck with that. And thatâs before we even start to make the tax progressive, to arrest or (gasp) reverse the increasing wealth and income concentration thatâs been delivered unto us by The Glorious Reaganomics Revolution. Markets on their own inevitably concentrate wealth, up to some very high level where open violent war and revolt break out. VAT-and-transfer can ameliorate that, but it canât ever correct or reverse it â even over decades, as the world pictures above make clear.
Are the Socks right, that we canât fund a full welfare state by taxing the rich? Absolutely. But âthat wonât solve everythingâ is never, ever, or anywhere a valid argument for âwe shouldnât do that.â Canât we, shouldnât we start by taxing the rich, then fill in with taxes farther down the spectrum?
To get a sense of what we could do, imagine taxing $1T a year from the top 20%Â â just 1.1% of their wealth. (To compare: portfolio holdersâ unearned total returns are generally in the range of 5% a year ++. Theyâd still keep getting richer if we pared off 1.1%, just more slowly.)
That $1T could deliver a modest universal income of $8,000 for every U.S. household, reliably, every year. It would completely transform tens of millions of lives. And because bottom-80 households turn over their wealth in annual spending 3â4 times as fast as top-20 households, the transfer would increase total national spending, economic activity, production, andâŠwealth accumulation.
Hereâs a look at how that tax and transfer would play out.1
After receiving their $8K UI payments (and paying taxes on them), the effective tax rate on top-20% wealth would only be 1%. Higher marginal propensity to spend would increase total consumption spending by 2%, every year (compared to the current status quo).
If you compound that 2% annual growth over ten or twenty years, you have a very big increase in GDP. And much of that increase would devolve to the top 20%. All boats rise. Funding the welfare state with progressive taxes, first, certainly looks like a better option â for all but the very richest.
How did Socks get to this point, focusing on regressive taxes to fund a robust welfare state, with progressive taxes more of an afterthought? (Afterthought at best, as itâs turned out.) The core story centers on postwar theories of âwelfare backlash.â Itâs well-described in Harold Wilenskyâs 2003 Rich Democracies, in particular Chapter 10, âTax-Welfare Backlash: How to Tax, Spend, and Yet Keep Cool.â
In short form, with a U.S. focus: the huge buildout of the welfare state under F.D.R. and his labor secretary, Frances Perkins, hit a wall after WWII, with the rise of âneoliberalismâ or whatever you choose to call it.
Socksâ both-sides-ism on the progressive/regressive question (âall taxes are good!â) can at least be seen as a capitulation to the counterattack launched by the Mount Pellerin Society in 1947, the 1971 Powell Memo, and zillionaire-funded astroturf propaganda campaigns that very much persist to this day. Democrats first abandoned their full-throated New Deal economic populism (that delivered four resounding Presidential wins for FDR) with Kennedyâs massive tax cuts for the rich in â64 â proleptically surrendering to âtrickle-down,â fifteen years before that term emerged.
And in the half-century post-LBJ (Medicare and Medicaid), the only significant economic-policy win for Socks has been the Frankenstein-monster âshopping will save us allâ free-market-hybrid abomination that is Obamacare.
American Socks also point out that the robust social democratic countries pretty much all rely on VATs. But a less-than-charitable description of how that happened in northern European social democracies starting in the â60s bears consideration. They ran screaming away from their progressive taxes in favor of VATs, effectively embracing and at least implicitly endorsing the âoptimal taxationâ notions of âThe Washington Consensus.â2
It was a political/electoral decision: if we (try to) tax the rich, theyâll fight back. So we should, in Wilenskyâs words, âkeep cool.â Considering the outcomes, itâs not all clear that Socks are such great experts on branding, political marketing, strategy, tactics, and the prediction of electoral results. Thereâs never even been a noticeable âSocial Democracyâ faction much less party in the U.S., postwar, outside of academia. Meanwhile the electorally disastrous brand âDemocratic Socialistsâ has surged as the only prominent voice of the full-throated left.
Coming back to the key takeaway here: if you think (highly) progressive taxes are a necessary or at least a good thing, and if you favor consumption/sales/VAT taxes, youâre going to have to plan on taxing top-quintile consumption spending at (high) double-digit or triple-digit rates. Itâs the only way the arithmetic works. The political/electoral math on that doesnât seem promising.
1 This doesnât consider every interacting effect. The UI, for instance, would reduce the need (and eligibility) for existing programs, which generally involve pernicious mechanisms for means-testing the poor. (This means-tests the rich instead, something we already do for income at least, on their annual tax returns.) That might reduce the need for the regressive taxes that generally fund those programs. A full workup is needed. But this presentation does accurately impart the magnitude, scale, and beneficial effects from such a tax-and-transfer setup.
2 Their basic argument: GDP = consumption spending plus investment spending. Y = C + I. If (profligate, irresponsible) C goes down because of a consumption tax, then (industrious, responsible) I must go up! See the logical error? Lower C will obviously cause producers to invest less. I and Y will both decline.