Monday , September 16 2024
Home / Real-World Economics Review / Price Gouging Part Two

Price Gouging Part Two

Summary:
From Peter Radford When you are only concerned with one thing and have only one tool things can go awry quite easily.  So it is with our price theory friends.  They bask in the rigor of their thinking and look askance at the inability of regular folks to grasp the point of the logic of their so-called price mechanism — note the mechanical nature of it all.  The recent spate of snooty commentary aimed at Kamala Harris and her ideas about price gouging are a case in point.  I talked about this a couple of days ago with respect to John Cochrane’s typical in-your-face article praising price gouging.  Cochrane typifies the defiance of a certain sort of economist.  They take pride in being determinedly anti-social and cast aspersions on anyone who dares to cross swords with their wisdom.

Topics:
Peter Radford considers the following as important:

This could be interesting, too:

Stavros Mavroudeas writes ‘Once again on the alleged differences between Engels and Marx’ – S.Mavroudeas, Beihang University, School of Marxism, Beijing, 11-9-2024

Editor writes The Chinese threat in critical minerals

tom writes Neoliberalism and the Drift to Proto-Fascism: Political and Economic Causes of the Crisis of Liberal Democracy

NewDealdemocrat writes Manufacturing and construction together suggest weak but still expanding leading sectors

from Peter Radford

When you are only concerned with one thing and have only one tool things can go awry quite easily.  So it is with our price theory friends.  They bask in the rigor of their thinking and look askance at the inability of regular folks to grasp the point of the logic of their so-called price mechanism — note the mechanical nature of it all.  The recent spate of snooty commentary aimed at Kamala Harris and her ideas about price gouging are a case in point.  I talked about this a couple of days ago with respect to John Cochrane’s typical in-your-face article praising price gouging.  Cochrane typifies the defiance of a certain sort of economist.  They take pride in being determinedly anti-social and cast aspersions on anyone who dares to cross swords with their wisdom.  Ignorance.  Gimmick.  Populist.  These economists are not short in vocabulary when someone treads heavily on their precious logic.

Which is all it is.  Logic.  Impervious to reality, but impeccable in its coherence.

The current controversy gives us an opportunity to look a bit more carefully at the shortcomings of economics and its obsession with what it calls markets.

One victim of putting all your emphasis on prices and their formation as the be-all and end-all of economics, along with the equilibrium that is claimed as the result of the suitable matching of supply and demand produced buy the movement of prices is production.

Economics has no theory of production.

As I have mentioned here before, some go as far as to claim there is no such thing as supply.  There is only demand.  This lunacy is entirely supportable by the logic of price theory.  Which is why price theory is a tender branch on which to balance the entire load of an economy.

You think I exaggerate?

Then allow me to refer you back to one of the primary sources of the current error.  The snootiness  began some time ago.  The arrogance set in during the 1930s.

Robbins, writing in 1932 about the application of what he refers to as the “new approach” — which is the relentless application of what we know as price theory to each and every nook and cranny of an economy, says the following:

“We may take as an example of the advantages of this procedure the modern treatment of organization of production.  The old treatment was hopelessly unsatisfactory: a few trite generalizations about the division of labor copied from Adam Smith, and illustrated perhaps by a few examples from Babbage; then extensive discursions on industrial “forms” and the “entrepreneur” with a series of thoroughly unscientific and question-begging remarks on national characteristics — the whole wound up, perhaps, with a chapter on localization. … “

Tell us what you think Lionel!  Who goes on:

“There is no need to dwell on the insufferable dreariness and mediocrity of all this.  But it is perhaps just as well to state definitely its glaring positive deficiencies.  It suggests that from the point of view of the economist “organization” is a matter of internal industrial … arrangement. … “

This is a polemic, so Robbins eschews the need to provide examples of all this shoddiness.  His point is unequivocal though.  It screams through his language:  There is one and only one source of organization in an economy: the price mechanism.  The structure of a firm, like everything else in the eye of price theorists, is a direct consequence of the playing out of prices.

When you only have a hammer …

Unless you missed the point Robbins carries on:

“In the modern treatment, discussion of “production” is an integral part of the theory of equilibrium.  It is shown how factors of production are distributed between the production of different goods by the mechanism of prices and costs…. The doctrine of division of labor, heretofore so disagreeably technological, becomes an integral feature of a theory of moving equilibrium through time.  Even the question of “internal” organization and administration now becomes related to an outside network of relative prices and costs; and since this is how things work in practice, what is at first sight the greater remoteness of theory in fact brings us much nearer to reality.”

Please stop laughing.  And I apologize for the extensive quotations.

Robbins is dismissing any need to develop a theory of production because everything falls under the rubric of prices.  In a sweeping and quite extraordinary way Robbins lays down a marker for all subsequent price theorists.  Nothing else matters.  Nothing.  Only the logic of the price mechanism.

Notice the slippery way he avoids the question of what to produce.  He simply says that resources are distributed amongst the different goods to be produced by the interplay of prices and costs.  But who decides what to produce?  That’s a decision that precedes such interplay.  For prices and costs to have an effect, they have to have an effect on something.  How does that something appear on the stage?  By magic?  There is no room for invention, innovation, or any other form of novelty in Robbins’ telling of the story.  He simply argues that prices and costs allocate resources amongst things that already exist.  His equilibrium and his logic are utterly incapable of explaining why economies change or why new products come into existence.  His theory and its successor versions are simply a logic, elaborately extended, that seeks to explain an entirely sterile view of market exchange.

Nor can he shed light on how to produce something.  He dismisses such talk as “disagreeably technological”.

No wonder economics has subsequently fumbled around with theories of the firm.  When you dismiss organization as being trivial and production as being only an extension of the allocation of resources subject to prices and costs beyond the boundaries of a firm, you disable any sensible or searching inquiry into such organization.

This crippling of economics and its turn into a narrow study of the logic of exchange rules out vast swathes of economic activity.  It reduces the relevance of economics to a sliver of the entire process of invention, production, consumption, and decomposition of the products that flow through a modern economy.

When you only have the hammer of the prince mechanism, everything does begin to look like demand.  You have dismissed the issues of supply as uninteresting and of no consequence.

Price theory, in its most logical form, is simply a method to study allocation of things that already exist and in places that already exist.  It stands mute on novelty.

Which is why Cochrane can claim that price gouging is a good thing.  Why?  Because the existing supply is allocated best when that last unit to be sold goes to the highest bidder — in Cochrane’s story it was the last available room in a motel.  In the mind of an economist “scarcity” has been eliminated and an optimal allocation achieved.  In the mind of everyone else, because no new supply has been called forth, the scarcity persists and the high price used to allocate that last product, deviating as it does from preceding or “regular” prices, is price-gouging at its worst.

In another setting, the bias of price theory becomes an ideological focus when a politician like Harris dares suggest that, perhaps, the discussion of how to deal with inflation has more than one leg to it.  Traditional economics places the entire burden on fighting inflation on demand.  Rising inflation requires, in this telling, dampening down demand.  In the real world this means making some portion of the working population unemployed and reducing wage increases.  This follows precisely from the sort of analysis that price theorists use.  After all, following Robbins, they have no insight into production and thus no insight into supply.  As some of them say: there is only demand.  In this case that demand emanates from pesky workers.

Parenthetically, there is a tawdry irony at play here: tenured academics lecturing us all on the importance of flexible labor markets and the need to adjust to locate an equilibrium seems somewhat hypocritical.  They seem able to ignore this without too much self-awareness though.

So the suggestion that some attention ought be given to the supply side of the equation is met with ribald laughter from the price theory crowd.  Their protestations of ignorance and meddling on the part of silly politicians is based on the security of their logic.  After all if there is no supply and only demand, and if production is subsumed as part of the market, it is folly to suggest taking a look at supply.  It doesn’t exist!

Which is convenient for the producers.  They don’t have to share in the pain of dealing with inflation. The economic experts say so.

Robbins blazed the path in more than one way.  Notice how that last long quote ends.  He applauds the dismissal of production and all that disagreeable technology and goes onto claim that such dismissal, far from being an odd result of some distant and abstract theory, actually moves his analysis into accord with reality.

Yes, reality.  As perceived by economists.

And that is where we find the best insight into how economics can sometimes appear absurd.  Robbins actually imagines that elimination discussions of production makes economics more realistic.   After all when you latch onto prices as the only matter of consequence in an economy, and when you laud the inevitability of equilibrium as it optimal achievement, your view of reality has become sufficiently distorted that you can actually say something like that.  The psychologists must have theories of their own to explain this syndrome.  The Brest of us just call it weird.

Likewise Cochrane actually believes that scarcity has been erased by the extraordinary pricing we call price gouging despite not a scintilla of new supply being created.

It’s all relative.  And its all inevitable.  The logic is solid.  Surge pricing is good for us.  We must accept the consequences of our arrival at equilibrium.  Our price theorists know a thing or two about reality.

Well, maybe.

One last thing.

I believe it was John Holland — not a price theorist obviously —  who said that when a thing is in equilibrium it is dead.

He’s correct.  Does that mean that price-gouging is good only in dead economies?

Asking for a friend.

__________________

Those quotes above are from Robbins’ “An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science”

Peter Radford
Peter Radford is publisher of The Radford Free Press, worked as an analyst for banks over fifteen years and has degrees from the London School of Economics and Harvard Business School.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *