Thursday , November 21 2024
Home / Prime, Policy Research in Macroeconomics / Dealing with the health crisis: rationing and price controls

Dealing with the health crisis: rationing and price controls

Summary:
Nature of the Health Crisis The current health crisis has similarities to the Great Recession of 2008-2009, though fundamentally different.  The crisis ten years ago resulted from collapse of financial institutions, a purely human-made disaster whose solution should have been obvious.  The financial collapse provoked a severe contraction in aggregate demand in household spending and business investment.  The demand contraction led to under-utilisation in most sectors, which a fiscal stimulus would have resolved -- inadequate demand, idle production and workers, correctable by the public budget replacing private demand with public demand.

Topics:
John Weeks considers the following as important: ,

This could be interesting, too:

Robert Skidelsky writes Speech in the House of Lords Conduct Committee: Code of Conduct Review – 8th of October

Ann Pettifor writes Global Economic Governance: What’s “Growth” Got to Do with It?

Frances Coppola writes The West must no longer tolerate Israel’s human rights breaches

Ann Pettifor writes Blame economists for decades of false security

Dealing with the health crisis: rationing and price controls

Nature of the Health Crisis

The current health crisis has similarities to the Great Recession of 2008-2009, though fundamentally different.  The crisis ten years ago resulted from collapse of financial institutions, a purely human-made disaster whose solution should have been obvious.  The financial collapse provoked a severe contraction in aggregate demand in household spending and business investment.  The demand contraction led to under-utilisation in most sectors, which a fiscal stimulus would have resolved -- inadequate demand, idle production and workers, correctable by the public budget replacing private demand with public demand.

The current economic contraction represents a production crisis, a spreading contraction in output as people self-isolate and the government orders workplace and shop closures.  The essential impact on the economy is the restriction of economic activity leading to a sharp decline in incomes and demand, the opposite causality of 2008-2009.  Some, including Paul Krugman, have called this a "supply side" crisis.  I avoid that terminology because of its unfortunate association with neoliberal ideology, the dogma that deregulation, "supply side reforms", would stimulate production through increased "efficiency" generated by market competition.

Policy response

A production crisis implies that the policy response must include and go beyond income replacement schemes.  The UK government proposed and will implement legislation to replace 80% of the earnings of redundant employees.  Payment of a basic income to all citizens represents an alternative viewed by many as more effective. 

Compensating for loss of household income provides a necessary but not sufficient response to the production crisis.  People not working by definition means production not realised.  Production of essential goods such as food and other household necessities will continue as far as is possible.  Three sources of disruption immediately come to mind:

  1. spread of illness might create labour shortages in some sectors;

  2. transport and delivery systems could reach capacity constraints, and

  3. disruption of international trade flows could require greater reliance on national supply.

An increasing number of experts has pointed out that the globalisation created long supply chains render the UK production and supply system vulnerable to disruption.  The cost-cutting practice of minimising inventories is also an important source of vulnerability though less fundamental.  At the moment domestic production accounts for slightly over half the food consumed by UK households.

The three sources of disruption to the supply of essential production lead to obvious policy steps.  First, quantity rationing of essential productions requires urgent consideration and planning.  I am careful to use the modifier "quantity" because all market economies enforce rationing -- households and businesses ration purchases on the basis of price and income.  The UK government enforced quantity rationing by use of ration books during and after World War II.

Second, rationing implies price controls.  In the United States price and profit controls, administered by the Office of Price Administration, supported quantity rationing from the outset in 1941.  Prevention of excessive profits, "war profiteering", was a central part of price administration.  Harry Truman obtained the prominence to become Franklin Roosevelt's vice president in 1945 by his Senate hearings on war profiteering.  In Britain quantity rationing continued well after the end of WW II, formally ending in July 1954.

Third, the government should initiate a broad "industrial policy" pointed at increasing domestic production of essential household products and medical equipment.  This programme would include credit directed through commercial banks, price subsidies and price guarantees.  For agriculture adoption of a variant of pre-EU policy could enhance national production.  Stated briefly, the EU Common Agricultural Policy, which the British government joined when it became a member, involved measures to protect agricultural production by holding prices high and absorbing surpluses through official purchases. 

The UK's pre-1973 agricultural support system kept prices low. The government set a guarantee price, farmers sold on the open market, and were paid the difference between the support price and their market price.  The result was low consumer prices as farmers produced up to their limits with no surpluses for the government to absorb.

To be concrete, the UK government could create a Basic Necessities Control Board, with at least three parts, offices of 1) price regulation, 2) production management, and 3) labour supply.  The latter would avoid the suggestion to import 90.000 agricultural workers from Central and Eastern Europe. 

This latter proposal is extremely unwise -- during a pandemic importing people from countries desperately struggling to contain the spread of Covid-19.  It indicates a lack of common sense.  The obvious solution to shortages of agricultural labour -- and workers in essential sectors in general -- is decent pay and adequate housing for the coming months and training schemes for the longer term.  The same policy would act to overcome shortages of health workers.  Self-congratulatory references to the large number of non-UK NHS staff fail to mention that active overseas recruitment reflected an attempt to attract cheap labour to the under-funded NHS, with the result of draining essential skilled workers from poor countries.

Longer term responses

Central to my proposal is whether it would represent a transitory crisis response or a fundamental change in policy for the long term.  Changes clearly advantageous for the long term are

  1. domestic training of health workers (of residents of all national origins) rather than importing cheap labour from low-income countries,

  2. replacement of the EU agricultural support programme with a pre-1973 type system now that we are out of the Union, and

  3. legislation to facilitate a Basic Necessities Control Board that the government could initiate in an emergency.

Two major policy changes may seem discretionary but in my view highly desirable.  Price control or at least monitoring of basic commodities should become permanent practice, as should public provision of a small number of those necessities, for example heating, electricity and transport.

The recent macroeconomic stimulus and income support programme may mitigate the gathering recession.  The government should also address the inevitable production consequence of a lockdown, by purposeful intervention in commodity and service markets.

Professor John Weeks is Emeritus Professor, SOAS, London. His most recent book is “The Debt Delusion” (Polity). You can follow him on Twitter @johnweeks41.

John Weeks
Progressive Economists Group editor, prof emeritus SOAS, Univ London, author of Economics of the 1%

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *