Summary:
This post first appeared on Pieria in November 2013. Throughout history, humans have dreamed of plenty. They have longed for there to be abundant supplies not only of essentials, but of luxuries. The promise made to the Israelites wandering in the desert was that they would eventually come to a land “flowing with milk and honey”. And the vision of the New Jerusalem in Revelation is of riches beyond imagination. Recent forecasts of forthcoming abundance, too, have focused on the benefits. Imagine a world in which everything was so plentiful that not only the essentials of life but the luxuries, too, were free. There would be no need for money, because nothing could be bought or sold; and there would be no need to work, because there would be no need for income. And if
Topics:
Frances Coppola considers the following as important: abundance, Capital, saving, scarcity
This could be interesting, too:
This post first appeared on Pieria in November 2013. Throughout history, humans have dreamed of plenty. They have longed for there to be abundant supplies not only of essentials, but of luxuries. The promise made to the Israelites wandering in the desert was that they would eventually come to a land “flowing with milk and honey”. And the vision of the New Jerusalem in Revelation is of riches beyond imagination. Recent forecasts of forthcoming abundance, too, have focused on the benefits. Imagine a world in which everything was so plentiful that not only the essentials of life but the luxuries, too, were free. There would be no need for money, because nothing could be bought or sold; and there would be no need to work, because there would be no need for income. And if
Topics:
Frances Coppola considers the following as important: abundance, Capital, saving, scarcity
This could be interesting, too:
Frances Coppola writes Silvergate Bank – a post mortem
Peter Dorman writes Extending Capital to Nature, Reducing Nature to Capital
Frances Coppola writes Tether’s smoke and mirrors
Frances Coppola writes Trade, saving and an economic disaster
This post first appeared on Pieria in November 2013.
Throughout history, humans have dreamed of plenty. They have
longed for there to be abundant supplies not only of essentials, but of
luxuries. The promise made to the Israelites wandering in the desert was that
they would eventually come to a land “flowing
with milk and honey”. And the vision of the New Jerusalem in Revelation is
of riches
beyond imagination.
Recent forecasts of forthcoming abundance, too, have focused
on the benefits. Imagine a world in which everything was so plentiful that not
only the essentials of life but the luxuries, too, were free. There would be no
need for money, because nothing could be bought or sold; and there would be no
need to work, because there would be no need for income. And if everyone
believed that such “superabundance” would last forever, then there would be no
need to worry about the future – no need to save or prepare in anyway. There
would be no point in deferring consumption in expectation of future returns: in
a superabundant world, there could be no greater returns in the future.
Consumption would be the only virtue. It’s a hedonist’s idea of heaven.
But these “benefits” have a dark side. Price is a function
of scarcity. If everything is superabundant, nothing has a price – that is why
everything would be free, and money would be unnecessary. But price is also the
principal means by which we measure value. If there is no price mechanism, how
will we establish value? Would every good, every service be regarded as of
equal value? Or would the value of goods and services be determined by popularity
rather than price – what we might call the Facebook approach to valuation (the
most valuable product is that which gains the greatest number of “likes”)? Perhaps
“likes”, or clicks, or phone votes would become a new measure of value – a new
form of price. But what would happen to the goods and services that were less
“in demand”? Would producers that didn’t
have enough likes stop producing? If so, then a superabundant world would in important
respects be less abundant than our present scarcity-driven world. There would
be no shortage of goods and services, but there might be a serious shortage of
diversity. As Henry Ford put it, “you can have any colour you like as long as
it’s black”. Why bother to create diversity if it’s going to reduce your value?
And it is scarcity that creates the desire to innovate. In a superabundant
world, why would anyone bother to innovate? The greatest value would be
achieved by being a monopoly provider of a single standard good or service that
never changes. After all, if there are no alternatives, everyone likes you.
We’ve seen this before, in command economies: in East Germany, everyone liked
the Trabant, didn’t they?
In a superabundant economy, money would be unnecessary, both
as a medium of exchange and as a store of value. The irrelevance of money as a
medium of exchange follows from the fact that nothing would have a price –
though Facebook “likes” and their equivalent would act in some ways like a new
form of money. But the irrelevance of money, and indeed of all assets, as a
store of value is perhaps less obvious.
If superabundance is believed to last for ever, there is no
point in saving. Indeed, if everything is free, in what could you save? There
is nothing that can store value, because there is no value to be stored. The
value of an asset that can’t be consumed is given by the present value of the
consumption goods that it could purchase at some time in the future. If the
value of all consumption goods at all times in the future is zero, then the asset
is worthless. So in a superabundant world, all financial assets used as stores
of value would by definition be worthless. Some physical assets, such as fine
wines, art, antiques and jewellery would still have value because of their
scarcity – not everything can be abundant. But what would be their purpose?
They would have no purchasing power in the future, because everything is free.
You would do better to drink the wine, hang the picture on the wall, use the
antiques and wear the jewellery. At least that way you will gain pleasure from
your assets. There would only be any
point in saving if you believed that superabundance would come to an end at
some time in the future. The “hyperinflationary Armageddon” disaster stories
that are circulated
by investment advisers promote this belief. But if the future is superabundance,
it is the investment advisers themselves who face disaster. If superabundance makes saving pointless,
their industry is doomed.
Although we dream of abundance, we actually don’t like it. Abundance – especially if production is
automated – means that people don’t have to work. And that attacks our moral
beliefs about hard work being “good” and laziness “bad”. Abundance means there
is no point in saving. And that attacks our moral beliefs about thrift being
“good” and profligacy “bad”. Abundance means that things we now consider
valuable become worthless. And that attacks our moral beliefs about property
and ownership. For if everything is free and everything is abundant,
“ownership” is irrelevant, and defending property “rights” is ridiculous. What
is the point of “defending” something that anyone can get for free anyway?
No-one is going to take it from you.
Theft is nonsensical in an abundant world.
Of course, I am describing an extreme world. But we are
already a long way down this road. Larry Summers observed that the rate of interest that would sustain full employment has
been negative for a long time and shows no sign of reversing. There has been
considerable discussion of an “excess of capital” that forces down interest
rates because it doesn’t have a productive home. But Randall Wray turns
this round: for him, it’s not an excess of capital but a shortage of
productive investment opportunities that is the difficulty. The problem is that
“capital is way too productive”. The amount of capital needed to produce all
the goods and services for which there is demand is falling – fast. This is
happening partly because production itself is becoming cheaper and more
efficient, but partly also because of the labour “glut” that cheaper and more
efficient production causes. In Western economies, wages are stagnating and
full employment has become a thing of the past: unemployment and – perhaps more
importantly – under-employment have become entrenched.
All of this is consistent with a trend to abundance. It is
not so much that people will no longer need to work as that there will be
little paid work for them to do (though that doesn’t mean that they can’t do
useful and productive things). And it is not so much that people will no longer
need to save, and companies will no longer need to generate profits, as that there
will be little need for the capital that they wish to invest. As the
productivity of both labour and capital increases, the need for them
diminishes. This is why the economy is creating bubbles. Those with assets are
desperately looking for yield, and
governments are desperately trying to generate jobs. Like animals in a drought,
investors and governments crowd into the last remaining waterholes, as the
water in them gradually evaporates.
This is a world of plenty. We have all we need, and we can
create all we need. Yes, there are pockets of scarcity – energy, for example,
and minerals, and even water. But all of these are problems that can be solved.
The question is whether we really want to. For the scarcities that we hang on
to, and that we create through artificial support of asset prices and
systematic rigging of markets, are all that separates us from our familiar
world and the desert of plenty.
Related reading:
The implications of secular stagnation – Gavyn Davies
The economy almost certainly needs bubbles – Monetary
Realism
Image from Wikipedia.